Tag Archives: roy harrod

Roy Harrod On The Balance-Of-Payments Constraint

I am always interested on how close economists come on a full model of how the world works. And so I found this passage from John McCombie in his article Harrod, Economic Growth And International Trade on Roy Harrod in the book Economic Dynamics, Trade And Growth: Essays On Harrodian Themes interesting:

Harrod, through the development of his open economy model, implicitly saw the fallacy of Keynes’s argument. On the basis of a model with no government sector, Harrod (1948, p. 103) noted that ‘the balance of trade depends upon whether the ratio of the volume of exports to the volume of home investment is greater or less than the ratio of the propensity to import (viz. imports represented as a fraction of income) to the propensity to save’. But there was no reason why, at full employment, these ratios should be equal and why the balance of payments should be in equilibrium. If there was initially a balance-of-payments disequilibrium, and it was impossible to finance perpetually the deficit, there would be a financial crisis and ‘investment would come tumbling down’. It is here that we perhaps have the first reference to the possibility of a balance-of-payments constraint, where conditions in the external markets dictate the level of domestic activity. Harrod also appreciated early on the deflationary bias which the balance-of-payments imposed on the international system, with the burden of adjustment falling on the deficit countries and where there was little to force a surplus country to expand its level of economic activity.

References

Harrod, R.F. (1948), Towards a Dynamic Economics, London: Macmillan.

Roy Harrod by Esteban Pérez Caldentey

If you’ve worked with Post-Keynesian models of the open economy, you’ll see the expression X/μ often. This, or the “foreign trade multiplier” was first discovered by Roy Harrod in the early ’30s.

Esteban Pérez Caldentey has a new biography of Roy Harrod.

Description:

This landmark book describes and analyzes the original contributions Sir Roy Harrod made to fields including microeconomics, macroeconomics, international trade and finance, growth theory, trade cycle analysis and economic methodology. Harrod’s prolific writings reflect an astounding and unique intellectual capacity, and a wide range of interests. He became Keynes’ biographer and wrote a volume on inductive logic. At the policy level, Harrod played a central role in the formulation of the Keynes´ Clearing Union plan for international monetary reform. He also actively participated in British politics and government and gained recognition as an expert in the field of international economics. Yet, until now, Harrod has remained an underrated economist, commonly misunderstood and misrepresented. This is the first major intellectual biography of Harrod to be published.

I found an interesting bit from the book. From page 259:

He [Harrod] also introduced the asymmetry of adjustment between creditor and debtor which was pivotal to Keynes’s Clearing Union proposal.

The asymmetry of adjustment is in my view one of the most important concepts to understand in economics. From The Collected Writings Of John Maynard Keynes, Volume XXV: Shaping The Post-War World: The Clearing Union, Chapter 1, The Origins Of The Clearing Union, 1940-1942, pages 27-30:

III. The Analysis of the Problem

I believe that the main cause of failure (except in special, transient conditions) of the freely convertible international metallic standard (first silver and then gold) can be traced to a single characteristic. I ask close attention to this, because I should argue that this provides the clue to the nature of any alternative which is to be successful.

It is characteristic of a freely convertible international standard that it throws the main burden of adjustment on the country which is in the debtor position on the international balance of payments,—that is on the country which is (in this context) by hypothesis the weaker and above all the smaller in comparison with the other side of the scales which (for this purpose) is the rest of the world.

Take the classical theory that the unlimited free flow of gold automatically brings about adjustments of price-levels and activity between the debtor country and the recipient creditor, which will eventually reverse the pressure. It is usual to-day to object to this theory that it is too dependent on a crude and now abandoned quantity theory of money and that it ignores the lack of elasticity in the social structure of wages and prices. But even to the extent that it holds good in spite of these grave objections, if a country is in economic importance even a fifth of the world as a whole, a given loss of gold will presumably exercise four times as much pressure at home as abroad, with a still greater disparity if it is only a tenth or a twentieth of the world, so that the contribution in terms of the resulting social strains which the debtor country has to make to the restoration of equilibrium by changing its prices and wages is altogether out of proportion to the contribution asked of its creditors. Nor is this all. To begin with, the social strain of an adjustment downwards is much greater than that of an adjustment upwards. And besides this, the process of adjustment is compulsory for the debtor and voluntary for the creditor. If the creditor does not choose to make, or allow, his share of the adjustment, he suffers no inconvenience. For whilst a country’s reserve cannot fall below zero, there is no ceiling which sets an upper limit. The same is true if international loans are to be the means of adjustment. The debtor must borrow; the creditor is under no such compulsion.

… Thus it has been an inherent characteristic of the automatic international metallic currency (apart from special circumstances) to force adjustments in the direction most disruptive of social order, and to throw the burden on the countries least able to support it, making the poor poorer.

I conclude, therefore, that the architects of a successful international system must be guided by these lessons. The object of the new system must be to require the chief initiative from the creditor countries, whilst maintaining enough discipline in the debtor countries to prevent them from exploiting the new ease allowed them in living profligately beyond their means.

The book also says that Roy Harrod was a life long believer of free trade. It’s a bit shocking!